1/1/12
–
On
12/31/11 the S&P 500 closed at 1258, resulting in a total return of 2.1% for
the year. All of this return came from dividends. The year starts with
continuing sovereign debt problems in Europe. We will therefore first analyze
possible significant events and then discuss our current asset allocation to
stocks, given the situation.
The
Eurozone was founded by the Treaty of Maastricht in 1992. At that time, the
founders hoped that their currency union would evolve into a political union.
The currency union was a success, but the Council of Ministers failed to apply
sanctions against France and Germany for continually violating their 3%
government deficit/GDP guidelines and never fined Portugal (2002) and Greece
(2005). In 2010, the Eurozone’s average deficit/GDP
ratio was 6%.
Both
Eurozone finances and the U.S. system of derivative structured mortgage finance
illustrate the idea that a theoretically flawed system can muddle through for
years, provided it’s foundation isn’t too compromised. What cracked the U.S.
financial system was (literally) a wholesale and reckless disregard for mortgage
credit standards. What cracked the Eurozone was the admission of Greece, that had large deficit problems, and private credit
and real estate bubbles in Ireland and Spain, the former requiring a large
government bailout of its banks. These collapses called into question the
markets’ conventional wisdom that the finances of all Eurozone countries were
equally sound. In the U.S., Mr. Market’s conventional wisdom was that house
prices would never decline.
In
finance, the conventional wisdom is a straight line. People either believe that
things will get better or worse forever 1, transitioning abruptly
between the two as circumstances affect the emotions of fear and greed. In the
Eurozone crisis, the markets now believe the worst. To be logical, that is to
keep your head while others are losing theirs, it’s useful to analyze what
engineers call the system’s failure points to investigate in a more detailed
fashion what might happen.
There
are two major failure points in the Eurozone. The first is the banking system,
and the second is an member state default or
exit.
Failure
of the Banking System
The
balance sheets of European banks are highly leveraged. The leverage of an European bank may be 2-3 times higher than that of U.S.
banks’. What justified this were two things: Advanced risk management practices
(scratch that) and less risky investments in sovereign debt (that is what this
is about). The European Banking Authority will require that their banks raise
$150 billion in additional capital.
This
is equal to the capitalization of one large U.S. bank, not at all meaningful for
an economy that is just slightly smaller than the U.S.’s. We suspect more
capital will actually be required to return the banks to health. On December 5,
the European Central Bank significantly promised to supply its banks with three
years of liquidity financing. The Fed will also make dollars available to the
central banks to prevent a seize-up of the international financial system. The
central banks have decided that there will be no “Lehman moment.” We’ll take
them at their word. We think the banking system is well enough backstopped;
although (to use a polite phrase) there will be some volatility if individual
banks get into trouble.
Member
State Default or Exit
If
you see on television the demonstrations in the streets around the world, not
just Athens, you are looking at the toll that financial excesses have caused.
That might also be a moment to reflect on how effective institutions really do
matter to keep a society functioning (also to give the U.S. stock market an
average around which it can fluctuate).
Imbalances,
that is
a lack of equilibrium - static or dynamic, lie at the root of the Eurozone
crisis. These imbalances need to be cured in both the short and long runs.
In
the short run, many countries of the Eurozone now have credit problems. Italy,
with the third largest economy in the Eurozone, is too big to fail. Countries
that try to leave the Euro will assuredly destroy their banking systems. On
rumor, their citizens will try to withdraw their bank deposits and convert them
into foreign Euros.
A
better solution is to have the ECB issue short-term guarantees of government
debt. That would facilitate future financings, automatically improve bank
balance sheets and let existing long-term debt accurately reflect the efficacy
of the political and economic reforms that have to occur. The current problem is
an ECB mindset that sees itself as responsible only for the Eurozone banks, not
as a lender of last resort to governments. This excerpt from the 12/15/11 ECB website shows a certain
head-in-the-sand attitude. In contrast, during the Financial Crisis of 2008, the
U.S. Fed supplied $7.77
trillion in guarantees and loans, 55% of GDP, to the financial system.
In
the long run, as in the U.S., the public has to accept difficult entitlement and
growth reforms. But the Eurozone countries are now being asked to give up their
budget sovereignty; the proposed administrative measures of sanctions and fines
are draconian if applied. They do not take into account the fact that Europe is
comprised of countries. The attempt to impose a larger political order on
Europe, that has scant public support, is a reach too far.
A
long-term solution to this crisis could look like this: Manage by setting
limits. Countries will maintain their sovereignty if they can access the credit
markets at acceptable terms and comply with a budget deficit limit set higher
than 3% 2. If not, the IMF or EU will encourage them to properly
maintain their properties in the Eurozone condominium. Right now, the Eurozone
won’t put much money in a deal to rescue themselves.
This is really a problem.
What
does this mean for investors? In spite of a few tentative “green shoots of
recovery” beginning to appear in the United States, the short-term behavior of
your investments will depend on the uncertain events developing across the
Atlantic, which will be ongoing. Here is a really useful general
rule for your investment money, also noted by John Bogle of Vanguard: The bond 3 percentage of
your portfolio should equal your age. The percentage of stocks will therefore
equal (100-bond percentage). Most people should probably target a minimum of 20%
stocks in their portfolio.
Given
the above, we are comfortable with being invested in stocks at around 40% of
target. This means that if the stock market drops by 30%, the portfolio will
drop by a tolerable amount. Those who can’t stand any loss should stay in a
laddered portfolio of bonds, but that is generally a bad idea – particularly
since good stocks now yield more than 3%. Stocks are a source of income and
an hedge against long-term inflation.
The
applicable motto is: Hope for the best, but prepare for the worst.4
In Europe, the best could occur after the worst truly threatens.
1
In
The General Theory (1935), Keynes wrote
about long-term expectation. “It would be foolish, in forming our expectations,
to attach great weight to matters which are very uncertain. It is reasonable,
therefore, to be guided to a considerable degree by the facts about which we
feel confident…For this reason the facts of the existing situation enter, in a
sense disproportionately into the formation of our long-term expectations; our
usual practice being to take the existing situation and to project it into the
future *, modified only to the extent that we have more or less definite reasons
for expecting a change.”
*
Value investors do this as well, building in a margin of safety, but only for
companies that have sustainable competitive advantages. All empirical
quantitative analysis has, in some sense, to be historically based. Natural
science analysis is based upon tables of correlated experimental numbers, from
which laws. In the social sciences, additional considerations relevant to the
ordering of society, the values of fairness and justice, also enter. These two
values are usually implicit in political discussion.
2
In
the difficult circumstances of 2010, the average Eurozone budget deficit was 6%,
which could be about right for some sort of country upper limit. Out of the
seventeen Eurozone nations, only Finland complied with the 3% limit.
3
add: A laddered bond portfolio
differs from an intermediate term bond mutual fund. Laddered bond portfolios are
comprised of individual bonds that are chosen to expire a set
intervals, say in one year, two years…etc. As a result, the portfolio
will continually be provided with liquidity for reinvestment at then current
interest rates. Given currently low interest rates, we would definitely look
into this type of bond portfolio to avoid large losses when rates rise in the
future. This type of portfolio, containing only bonds of good credit quality,
needs to be set up with the aid of financial specialists.
4
This
military motto is risk-adverse.
__
From
the feedback we’ve been getting, the article above has been received by some of
our readers with a degree of concern. This is because people like certainty.
Social institutions exist to make life more predictable. But the Financial
Crisis of 2008 is now eroding the public system, including the system of
sovereign debt. There are two possible solutions for restoring economic
growth.1 The simple solution is to seek the
restoration of that growth by slogans that relate to second-order economic
effects such as, “no new taxes,” or, “get government out of the way.” The last
thing that people who really start new companies think about is the tax on
expected profits. The U.S. now faces economic competition from highly
government-directed societies. The effective solution is to directly confront
the problem: reduce the growth in debt by making difficult fiscal reforms and
restore economic growth by making social changes: changes in education,
industrial structure, and government trade policies. The culture wars really get
in the way of this.
The
Financial Crisis of 2008 is compromising the institutions of society; and, as is
happening in Europe, these social compacts have to be renegotiated. This, of
course, creates investment uncertainty. There is no getting around this. The
best we can do as equity value investors is to balance the
add: system rewards and the risks. These risks will not go
away for a long time; they are perhaps more characteristic of the developing
markets. This is a complicated time when only a balanced rationality will get us
out of present circumstances. The alternative is chaos or revolution, but the
latter also has its costs.
Election
year politics is not subtle; it is simple. However, if forced to make a choice
between, “Government” or “No Government,” we would
choose the former to make room for future solutions.
1
Also low-risk assets yielding decent rates of return
↓ WE ALSO SUGGEST THE FOLLOWING: ↓
2/1/12
–
On
1/20/11 we began to increase our equity allocation from around 40% of target to
70% of target. The attitudes of the negotiators from both Greece and the EU are
constructive, and we think it likely that they can reach an agreement that will
enable disbursements of a €130 billion loan to proceed. Both Greece and Portugal
together account to only 3.3% of the Eurozone’s GDP,
but the stakes for the major Eurozone economies are huge. With a combination of
both ECB and IMF funding (the Eurozone countries are expected to provide more
than half of the latter) and some structural reform in Athens, the Eurozone is
gradually getting control of their problems in their own way. add: The FT later suggests a better way.
This
cultural distinction is crucial, and is an opportunity to briefly discuss how
capitalism on the Continent differs from the Anglo-American market model, that
(for better or worse) maximizes freedom. The American model is one of trial and
error, based upon effective institutions. The net result is a dialectic, or
dialogue, where changing circumstances modify institutions and vice-versa
(provided ideology doesn’t get in the way).* This
market system is highly creative, but also inefficient. Under this system
individual economic actors are in an often wasteful competition, but the entire
system effectively adapts to a changing environment.
►The
American institutional solution for the Eurozone market crisis was simple and
clear. Provide central bank guarantees to restore market
confidence.
Germany
is the premier economy on the Continent. Its evolution was, of course, shaped by
its culture but also by the fact that it came late to the game of economic
competition. The economic modernization of Germany provided a highly relevant
model to the developing world that persists, via Japan, to this day in Asia. In
a really notable article titled, “Ideas, Institutions and Organized Capitalism,”
Christopher Allen writes:
One
can tell a great deal about the organization of a nation’s economic policy
by understanding the country’s timing of industrialization and
democratization. Countries that industrialized early tended to have
laissez-faire free market economies that gradually evolved into the
world’s leading economies because their good fortune and path-breaking
industrialization allowed them to have relatively easy access to
resources, markets, and capital. The UK and the U.S. are the prime
examples of this pattern. Countries that industrialized later, such as
Japan, faced a different set of choices. Lacking ready and predictable
access to resources, markets, and capital, they needed to construct a
different set of institutions if they were to catch up to the earlier
industrializers. In short, they needed to
construct a model that maximized efficient access and use of resources,
targeted foreign markets since their own domestic markets were so
underdeveloped, and allocated capital so that each investment had a high
probability of success. Unlike the “trial and error” economies of the
earlier industrializers, the latecomers had much
less margin for error...”Trial-and-error” capitalism was simply not
sufficient or fast enough (our note)….because production for
domestic consumption was a second order priority, providing some sort of
social protection for the majority of citizens who were not favored in
these top-down…systems was crucial. In essence, this was an ‘all eggs in
one basket” economic policy-especially during the nondemocratic Bismarckian era - that required close coordination of
all major producers and the emphatic provision of social order.
** |
This
was a state-directed autocratic capitalism that involved the close cooperation
between producer and financial groups where, “Bismarck used the state more as an
architect, rather than in an interventionist, micro-managing way.” Combined with
aggressive nationalism, this system contained the seeds of its own ruin in two
World Wars. In the postwar period, Germany developed a state-directed democratic
capitalism, for the same reasons as above, but including other social
organizations such as the trade unions and their allies. In the 1990s, its
social market economy began to erode in the face of globalization, the expansion
of the EU, and most important, the stresses of unification.
The
Financial Crisis of 2008 has now placed both the Anglo-American and the
Continental Europe economic models at question. Mohamed El-Erian writes in the FT that critics conclude, “…the crisis
in capitalism is caused by two distinct failures: the inability of the system to
deliver sustained prosperity through economic growth and jobs; and the
perception that it is grossly unfair and socially unjust…(raising) legitimate
questions about the model itself.”
►What
the United States sees as “dithering” is an attempt by the Europeans, and
Germany in particular, to create a sound “architecture” of Eurozone institutions
to meet new challenges. That is, to cut to the chase, mercantilist Germany gains
such overwhelming benefits from the Euro - an undervalued currency and trade
surplus - they will ultimately “pay anything” *** to keep the Eurozone intact
until the economic reforms they advocate become a reality.
Given
the number of parties involved, this task will be slow and difficult. In
contrast, the American challenge is somewhat easier, if ideology doesn’t get in
the way, because its society is more simply organized around markets and founded
upon institutions that require relatively moderate reform to become again
effective. In specific, financial regulation needs to be improved; the social
contract has to be slightly renegotiated; and the state has to become more
involved in trade policy and investments for the future (as the Friedman book
and Keynes suggested).
We
think that a certain degree of optimism about the future is not misplaced.
Relative to other societies, provided reform is not blocked, the United States
has a more adaptable and coherent social system.
* In 1943, Churchill said, “First we
shape our buildings and then they shape us.” We think this idea is
important.
**
This
article by Christopher Allen was published in the journal, “German Politics
and Society,” Summer, 2010 issue. It is well worth your
time if you are interested in how the economies of different societies are
organized.
***
This is the view of Fred Bergsten, director of the Peterson Institute. He also
discusses a question that interests us greatly. Why do experts disagree? A
former U.S. government official said people disagree because of different
philosophies and life experiences. Mr. Bergsten, more specifically, says that
this is because of using different models. Pessimists about the Eurozone
critique the system using an “optimal currency model,” no currency adjustment
within the Eurozone therefore disaster. Mr. Bergsten, we think properly, uses a
more general political economic model that starts with the culture and interests
of those involved. Which model is
right? The one that is closer to reality and therefore has the
intended consequences.
__
These 12/2011
Fed statistics state the obvious. Total lending is growing but slowly, the
amount of real estate credit (securities and lending) has decreased, but lending
to the industrial sector is growing rapidly. This suggests to us that led by the
industrial sector, the “green shoots of recovery” might finally persist after
four difficult years because growth begets growth - absent major problems in
Europe. However this recovery is anemic because usually housing leads and the
total rebound is greater because both housing and business investment
increase. *
U.S. Bank Lending (billions of dollars)
1
|
12/2010 |
12/2011 |
%
Change |
Total
Bank Credit |
9,205 |
9,416 |
+ 2.3 |
All
Real Estate Credit 2 |
4,874 |
4,863 |
-
.2 |
Commercial
and Ind. Lending |
1,215 |
1,338 |
+10.1 |
|
|
|
|
2
Sum of lines 4,7,11 |
|
|
|
1 Federal Reserve 2/3/12 Call
Report (p.2), seasonally adjusted
About value investing: Invest when prospects are bright and the sky is sunny? That is momentum investing, betting the market will increase from a P/E of 21. Invest when prospects are not so bright and the sky is cloudy? This is value investing when the market is around a P/E of 13. Value investors don’t mind investing into problems – at the right price. We did not invest when the market was at a P/E of 8 because the financial system was at question.
* By complaining about anemic economic growth, the Republicans really aren’t complaining about too much government. They are complaining that the U.S. isn’t building many more houses. It is contradictory to say that government should just let housing prices bottom and implicitly advocate building more houses to boost growth.
The
above considers the U.S. stock market from a cyclical standpoint. The major
issues facing the economy are long-term structural, requiring a role for
government. The U.S. needs more than non-exportable houses to restore
growth.
There
is also a systems issue. Both evolving institutions and free markets error
correct. When effective institutions error correct, as we demonstrated in How the U.S. Stock Market Works, the
moderate change that conservative Edmund Burke valued results. But, as the
Financial Crisis of 2008 demonstrated, when markets error correct they can –
with globalization – destroy worthy companies and whole economies. Imagine what
would happen if the market lost faith in the U.S. dollar due to large continued
trade imbalances. This is why error correction by effective institutions is much
better than error correction by panicked markets. Look at what is happening in
the Eurozone.
–
The
alphabet international organizations: The ECU, ECB, and IMF Troika, the Eurozone
central banks and private lenders will likely reach agreement and lend an additional €130
billion, provided Greece increases its austerity. That does not solve the basic
problem of insufficient growth. The following IMF projections show that at least
2.5% real economic growth will be required for it to be able to reduce debt to
120% of GDP by 2020. But Greece has an import
economy and may not be able to implement the necessary structural
reforms.
Greece: Fifth Review 12/31/11 Revised Baseline Scenario (IMF report,
page 71)
Year |
2011 |
2012 |
2013 |
2014 |
2015 |
2016-2020 |
Assumed
GDP Growth |
-6.0%* |
-3.0% |
0.4% |
1.9% |
2.5% |
2.5%
+ |
Public
Debt as % GDP
|
161% |
162% |
155% |
152% |
147% |
142%-120%** |
*
-6.8% (A) **
IMF research suggests, “105 to a maximum of 120 percent of GDP as a
sustainable range for debt in market access
countries.” |
This
means, as the situation now exists, the Greek financial
crisis will likely be ongoing. If it proceeds on this course, the Eurozone needs
to fence off the problem, to reduce contagion to other financial
markets.
It is estimated that seventy percent of the Eurozone’s
new loan will be earmarked to paying off Greece’s existing debtors, less recent
writeoffs. How long can this go on? The 2/10/12 FT points out a crucial fact. Greece’s primary
budget balance is due to go positive this year meaning before debt service
costs; they won’t need foreign capital.
Greece: Fifth Review 12/31/11 Revised Baseline Scenario (IMF report, page
71)
Year |
2011 |
2012 |
2013 |
2014 |
2015 |
2016-2020 | ||
Assumed
GDP Growth |
-6.0%* |
-3.0% |
0.4% |
1.9% |
2.5% |
2.5%
+ | ||
Primary
Balance** as % GDP
|
-2.2% |
+.2% |
+2.6% |
+4.5% |
+4.5% |
+4.5-4.3% | ||
|
*
-6.8% (A) **
% Revenues – % non interest expenditures. The corporate equivalent of this
is % net operating income. |
| ||||||
It
is useful to note the goal of the judicial Chapter 11 bankruptcy process in the
United States and now similarly in England. The goal of bankruptcy is practical,
to rehabilitate the debtor. This negotiated process results in a restructured
corporate balance sheet. The company is then able to start anew.
Even
though their government has a present problem with trust, the Greeks deserve
more than a foreclosed future. The FT article simply suggests, “The Eurozone
could press ahead with the steepest possible restructuring of privately held
Greek debt – and drop its pretence that it be voluntary – then stand behind
whatever remains by funding an escrow account for debt service. No more money
need to be sent to Athens…Greeks could (then) choose
for themselves how to continue their painful adjustment to economic reality.” *
The net result is that the Eurozone will be guaranteeing itself for the
remaining debt. With this, everyone – including the Eurozone itself - will be
forced to own up to their mistakes. Before chargeoffs,
Greek public debt is around 4.1% of the Eurozone total.
A
problem with the idea of debt cancellation is that other countries, for instance
Portugal or Ireland, could demand the same deal. The problems of fairness,
however, pale beside the problem of trying to impose a draconian Treaty of
Versailles on an increasingly unwilling Greek people. They should be able to
decide whether to stay in the Eurozone or leave.
*
This is the best solution for Greece and the Eurozone as a whole, but there are
conceptual impediments on the continent. This is no giveaway. Greece has not the
capacity to reduce its debts and will not be able to access the debt markets for
years. The alternative to substantial restructuring, now, is likely increased
social violence and a failed state on Europe’s doorstep. If you think this idea
is costly…
↓ WE ALSO SUGGEST THE FOLLOWING: ↓
3/1/12
-
On
2/21/12 the Eurozone ministers met in Brussels and approved a second €130
billion bailout for Greece. It is not likely that this will be effective because
it does not meet the requirements that the noted classicist, Donald Kagan, set for a durable peace treaty: First, the peace
treaty must reflect the true situation. Second, the principals must want to make
it effective. This bailout meets neither requirement. The Eurozone has dodged
the bullet of default; but all it has done is again kick the can down the road –
while shoring up the firewalls to avoid contagion. It would have been much
better if this bailout had been negotiated from the fundamentals. *
Since
many of our readers are invested in stocks, this is a good opportunity to
discuss two possible reactions to market declines. If you’re leveraged, you have
to be a trader. Because, whether the price of a stock declines due to events or
sunspots, the mere fact of decline can result in a margin call. Just ask MF
Global. If you are not leveraged, you have time to ask whether that market slide
is due to ordinary events that are inconsequential in the long-run (because you
have conviction, having done your homework) or due to overvaluation or financial
systems problems.
If
ordinary events cause a stock market decline, and there will be many, the best
advice is, “Roll with the punches.” We think the Eurocrisis is now in this category.
If
the cause of a beginning market decline is overvaluation or severe financial
systems problems, then it’s best to exit the stock market. Extreme overvaluation
generally occurs when the economy has been doing very well and Fed is on alert
to raise interest rates substantially to control inflation. Financial systems
problems are rare; but if they do occur – as they did in 1930, the 1970s, and in
2008 – they can obliterate a substantial portion of the economic system and your
portfolio. All these were caused by mistakes in economic regulation or policy,
involving both the Federal Reserve Bank and the political party then in power.
Isaiah
Berlin wrote that judgment is knowing when to act and
when not to. Good judgment is what Aristotle called practical wisdom, almost
always based upon the situation. In the last decade, many lost their lives and
others lost their livelihoods due to the bad judgment caused by blind political
ideology.
*
Why is the Eurozone being, to use a polite word, so “obtuse”? To but chide Germany slightly. A member of the opposition
Social Democratic party noted:
Angela
Merkel risks a revolt within her own party should she agree to any measures that might impose costs on German
taxpayers or diverge from German economic dogmatism, especially the mantra
of central bank independence. From the beginning of this crisis, the
involvement of the European Central Bank has been a sore point for
Germany. It has become a question of principle rather than a question
of economic reasoning (our note). To
outsiders this may astonishing…To cling to economic principles that
predate monetary union and the evident market failures of the past years
seems naïve at best, when considering the possible fallout….But to discuss
alternatives to Germany’s central banking dogmatism is taboo for Germany’s
right, regardless of advice from Nobel laureates and German economists.
|
What
Greece really needs is a German Marshall Plan; but, unfortunately, memories are
short. After W.W. II, the U.S. helped out Europe from an enlightened
self-interest.
__
Business
can be very constructive. The head of the German manufacturers’ association calls
for just this kind of Marshall Plan for Greece. This is different from playing
the kind of games that caused the Financial Crisis of 2008. In this video,
FT correspondent Martin Wolf discusses Greece’s horrific
alternative.
__
The
European process of forming a workable constitution is different from the
American experience in 1787. The delegates to the Constitutional Convention were
negotiating out of a common culture and historical experience, having just won
the Revolution. The Europeans do not have this positive commonality (neither,
apparently, does the U.S. Congress as presently constituted). Bergsten and Kirkegaard of the Peterson Institute write that the four
parties: the ECB, the creditor nations led by Germany, the IMF and the private
lenders are negotiating a deal by playing a massive game of chicken with each
other.* In this process they are trying to,
“…fundamentally reform the Eurozone institutions and structurally overhaul many
Eurozone economies.”
The
result is not going to be to be a crackup. “Europe’s key political actors…will
thus quite rationally exhaust all alternative options in searching for the best
possible deal before at the last minute coming to an agreement….Europe’s
overriding political imperative to preserve the integration project will surely
drive its leaders to ultimately secure the euro and restore the economic health
of the continent.” We discuss Europe in detail. Not only because it’s
interesting, illustrating how different cultures effect social order **, but
also to illustrate that equity investing is not riskless and that risk cannot be
precisely controlled (unless the whole world is Gaussian). Risks can be
categorized as either acute or Gaussian; the former to be avoided like the
plague, the latter kinds are controllable. Equity investing also requires
optimism.
*
The problem with this game is that uncontrollable circumstances can intervene,
plunging all into disaster. However, Bergsten writes, “The key to understanding
the evolution of the euro is to observe and analyze what the Europeans do rather
than what they say. They have solved all of the many crises that have threatened
the European integration project throughout its history of more than half a
century in ways that have strengthened the institutions and pushed European
integration forward. At each key stage of the current crisis, they have in fact
done whatever is necessary to avoid collapse….The ultimate political goals (of
Germany and the ECB)…assure this result.”
**
We obviously prefer U.S. freedoms. But, to also state the obvious, the reality
of the world is that cultures differ and different peoples have different ways
of settling conflicts and doing things. Judgment is knowing how and when to act
in real situations.
4/1/12
-
The
next problem is Iran. Its outcome has investment implications. We think that
serious negotiations with Iran will likely be successful because there is a
clear solution. Without boots on the ground, U.S. or Israeli military action to
take out Iran’s uranium enrichment facilities will only swat the hornet’s nest,
at most delaying its nuclear effort by a few years as the regime further
disperses and hardens its nuclear facilities against more outside intervention.
Military intervention, as a last resort, would drive the world economy into
another recession, further disrupt the fraught Mideast and hurt Iran more than
the rest of the world.
In
a talk at Columbia University, inventor and entrepreneur Steven Perlman said
that inventors formulate the right question to ask. From asking that question,
the answer naturally follows. * In the Iranian situation, the crucial question
is, “What policy will enhance the security of the United States, Israel, and
generally the Mideast?” If that is the question, bombing is a very imperfect
solution. It is more rational for all sides to seriously negotiate.
The
U.S. could simply take Iranians at their own word. Iran’s former spokesman for
the nuclear negotiating team, Sayed Hossein Mousavian (now at
Princeton, he’s obviously gotten reasonable), suggests:
Going
forward, any viable solution needs to meet the bottom lines of both sides.
For Iran, that means the ability to produce reliable civilian nuclear
energy as it is entitled to do under the non-proliferation treaty. For the
U.S. and Europe, it means never having Iran develop nuclear weapons or a
short-notice breakout capability.
Bloomberg, 2/16/12 |
This
means that Tehran should manufacture and stockpile only 4-5% enriched uranium
for energy production. Iran also claims it needs 20% enriched uranium for
medical and research purposes, from which weapons grade 90% + enriched uranium
can be manufactured with only slight additional effort; consider the second graph that
justifies only 4-5% enrichment. The U.S. could demand unconditional inspections
of any location* in Iran to be sure that no 20% enriched uranium is ever again
produced or stockpiled. It can then supply the Iranians with a tagged and
tracked quantity of 20% enriched uranium if necessary.
Are
the mullahs of Tehran rational? Fareed Zakaria answers, definitely:
Indeed,
Iran has been very calculating in its behavior, far more than other
so-called radical, revolutionary regimes….Their behavior for 30 years has
been calculating. They respond to inducements and pressures in ways that
are completely understandable. Their
goals are not ours, of course, but that’s a very different issue.
CNN, 3/8/12 |
There is a clear path out of this crisis,
but there will be a lot of bazaar haggling. Zakaria
makes a useful distinction:
A
rational actor is not a reasonable actor. It is not somebody who has the
same goals or values as we have. In
international affairs or economics, the term rational actor is used to
describe somebody who is concerned about their survival, prosperity or
strength and is making calculations on the basis of these concerns. It
describes someone who calculates costs and benefits.
|
Meir
Dagan, the former Director of Israel’s Mossad,
characterizes the Iranians he has met:
They
are rational, not in the western sense (thinking generally ? 1), but in the sense they think
through the implications of what they are doing (thinking about the
situation they are in? 2)
Right now, they are being very careful. They are maybe three years away from the bomb. 60 Minutes,
3/11/12 1
Also abstractly. 2
A
social scientist can think of
conditions. |
The
International Atomic Energy Agency is charged with implementing U.N. Security
Council resolutions. Their February 24, 2012 report indicates the current
inspection protocols are very porous due to the lack of Iranian cooperation. We
have reproduced the summary.
*
The 3/19/12 NYT mentions two caveats: 1) “…asking the right question only works
if you are prepared to hear answers you don’t like.” 2) “Sometimes (always, in the case of
ideology) our leaders start with the answers and work backward, fixing the facts
to the policy, as the head of Britain’s MI6 said of the Potemkin intelligence
used to sell the invasion of Iraq….If Iraq taught us nothing else, it should
have taught us this: Before you deploy the troops, deploy the fact-checkers.”
__
On
3/13/12, the Fed published the results of its CCAR
(Comprehensive Capital Analysis and Review) of the nineteen largest U.S. bank
holding companies. This analysis contains a lot of good news and some bad news.
Under a condition of major stress, to be later discussed, the Tier I common
capital ratio of all bank holding companies (incl. Goldman Sachs) dropped from
10.1% in Q3 2011 to a minimum of 6.8% in Q4 2013, a ratio of 5% being the
regulatory minimum. The U.S. financial system is sound. The further good news is
that all large commercial banks (J.P. Morgan Chase, Bank of America, Citigroup,
Wells Fargo, and BNY Mellon) survived a stringent stress test with estimated
Tier I common capital ratios above the minimum, assuming no capital actions such
as increased common dividends and share repurchases.
The
bad news is that Citigroup’s Tier I common capital ratio was a decent 5.9% in Q4
2013 assuming no capital actions. But with likely aggressive capital actions
(payouts) planned by management, that ratio dropped to 4.9%, the second worst in
the group of fifteen commercial bank holding companies similarly analyzed. By
planning premature capital payouts, Citigroup’s management probably made the
same mistake that Bank of America made in 2011. We invest in Citigroup for a
recovery in the U.S., its future growth potential in the developing world, and
its ability to replace capital; but we do think more patience on the dividend
side would have been appropriate.
The
Fed first assumed the following five major stress conditions: 1) Nominal GDP growth on an annualized
basis of -1.7% in Q4, 2011; decreasing to -5.39% in Q1, 2012 2) A Dow of 7089 in Q2, 2012 3) An unemployment rate of 13.05% in
Q2, 2013 4) A further decrease in house prices
of 20% between Q4, 2011 and Q1, 2014
5) A large decrease in
Eurozone GDP from -1% in Q4, 2011 to -6.91% in Q3, 2012.
How
to model the losses of large commercial and industrial loans? According to the
Fed report, “Losses on large commercial and industrial…loans are modeled by
estimating the impact of macroeconomic variables on the probability of default
for these exposures. The first stage of the modeling process is estimation of a
series of equations relating historical changes in the median probability of
default for 12 different borrower industries, six credit quality categories, and
countries of incorporation to
macroeconomic variables, including changes in stock price volatility and the
spread on BBB- rated corporate bonds. Default probability data are derived from
expected default frequency estimates….” We do not have technical experience with
econometric credit equations, but think the result of this analysis will be
consistent and generally useful.
Speaking
of social science conditions: This article
by Harvard Professor Larry Summers characterizes the current economic
recovery.
“Such recovery as we are enjoying is less a reflection of the natural resilience
of the American economy, than of the extraordinary steps that both fiscal and
monetary policy have taken to offset private-sector deleveraging – a process
that is far from complete.” Since no one can gauge the future with precision,
future macroeconomic policy has to be contingent. “The right approach is
policies that commit to normalizing conditions, but only when certain thresholds
are crossed. The Federal Reserve might commit to maintain the current Fed funds
rate until some (publicized) threshold with respect to unemployment or expected
inflation is crossed.…Tax reform could phase in new rates in pace with the
rising economic performance.”
5/1/12
–
Preliminary
discussions with Iran about their nuclear program have been “useful,” but not
yet specific. Iran and six other nations have agreed to meet later May in
Baghdad, where serious negotiations on proposals drafted by the EU and Iran will
begin.
U.S.
economic conditions are slowly improving. The IMF
Global Stability Map on page 2 of the 4/12 report also describes presently
improved European financial conditions. The Eurozone, the European Central Bank
and the IMF now all have firewalls to deal with credit problems in Spain or
Italy, that did not exist a year ago. However, some
Eurozone countries have severe structural problems; and there is a beginning
political backlash against economic austerity.
Policy
matters. Consider governments’ policy responses to the Financial Crisis of 2008,
having learned the lesson of the 1930s. In both the U.S. and Europe, the central
banks dodged the bullet of financial contagion bearing down upon them and
stabilized the system, by lending freely. But Europe is making a new mistake by
implementing country programs that impose years of fiscal austerity. It makes no
sense to free up resources (increase unemployment) if the economy doesn’t know
what to do with them, due to path dependence like losing export manufacturing. *
Severe austerity is appropriate only if there is no hope for future economic
growth. More constructively, Greece requires a viable export industry; and the
U.S. requires industry that can reduce imports.
Assuming
future U.S. economic growth, government can cushion downturns with appropriate
spending, plan for more growth and companies should be encouraged to invest in
the U.S. and its future. Both the U.S. and Europe require a mix of policies to
restore balanced economic growth. Taking a cue from how Asia developed, if we
had to focus upon one thing, the U.S. should encourage industry that can
gradually reduce imports.
Experience
from the Financial Crisis of 2008 might suggest that business confidence and
therefore markets are by nature fragile. The financial abuses were, however,
substantial. They are now being corrected, both by the markets and appropriately
by government. Because the U.S. is slowly recovering and there are European
firewalls, the yearly returns of the U.S. market are likely to exhibit a more
Gaussian distribution than in previous years.** The
stock market is also not expensive. Compare the S&P 500 P/E of around 1400 /
(estimated operating earnings of 100 or 110) with1990-2012 historical data
that included all sorts of economic environments.
add:
* The standard IMF formula for countries in trouble is both austerity and
devaluation, to free up resources and increase exporting potential. In the
Eurozone, austerity without devaluation inflicts hardship on all except Germany.
Previous economic recoveries after crises involved both economic restructuring
and controlled foreign exchange devaluations, a useful
example of
this is the Asian Financial Crisis of 1997. In the absence of foreign exchange
adjustments, Eurozone solutions have to be institutional.
As
value investors, we are skeptical of Mr. Market. As a reality check, we spoke
with a liberal economist with government experience who believes that markets
can bring about necessary economic readjustments (at the macro level). Our
latest article, “Economic Theory and Social Reality” suggests that the
unrealistic classical market model needs to be corrected by institutions. In
other words, both institutions and markets are necessary for economic growth;
the question to ask is how the markets can best be
corrected.
*
* That is, the market will still vary, but in a more bounded
way.
__
Does
the headline risk of a possible-likely Greek default warrant going to cash to
prevent a permanent loss of capital? We don’t think so. A long-term loss of
capital might result if the Eurozone were to totally unravel, due to financial
contagion. If Greece, then Spain, then Italy…then…. An important issue is this;
in the midst of turmoil, we don’t know what the European financial authorities
will do. add: Suddenly issuing blanket Eurobond
guarantees would (theoretically) solve the whole problem because the
Eurozone as a whole has only a very slight trade imbalance. We are willing to
withstand the volatility because the multinational companies we are invested in
have high cash flows therefore high returns on capital, and we got them at a
good price.
Possible
market volatility would provide only the opportunity to buy more stock; we’re
getting the benefit of dividends right now. This could be a useful moment of
truth. You have to decide whether you are an investor or a trader; you really
can’t be both. You’ve got to know yourself and decide; it’s really that simple.
Also, being appropriately asset allocated doesn’t hurt.
__
Rioting
in the streets does not add to confidence in the Euro. Of crucial importance is
what Germany will do. If the Euro disappeared, the Deutschmark would be the only
major store of value on the continent. It would then appreciate, pricing German
exports out of the market. If the unthinkable happened and Greece left the
Eurozone, the remaining countries would have to protect themselves from
contagion by accelerating their institutional and economic integration – such as
a banking union (add: at least),
Eurobonds, and a unified fiscal policy. These are difficult but not impossible.
Our
analysis of the situation looks something like this: (+)
Stocks are good value. It’s in Germany’s interest to keep the Euro. (-)
Greece exits. The Eurozone implodes.
In this analysis, the seconds cancel out. Therefore, balance the value of
stocks against a Greek exit. Which finally addresses the
fundamental, balance the gains from long-term value investment against the
losses averted from short-term trade.
Pimco expects the central banks to keep rates low, at
least for a while. Therefore to earn anything on your capital, you will have to
accept some volatility and maybe some risk. Take note of an asset allocation
that is appropriate and that you are comfortable with; note that there are no
longer any 5% low-risk bank savings accounts.
6/1/12
– U.S.
housing starts, employment, and corporate/industrial lending are beginning to
recover. However, these political events likely retard the market (add: and the economy) over the short-term:
1)
Greece - At this writing, polling indicates that the centrist, pro-bailout ND
and PASOK parties might have a majority of 11 to 16 seats in the 300 seat
parliament. The perception may be growing that Greece must recognize its
commitments in order to stay in the Euro. Greece could then continue to be
engaged in negotiations with the rest of the Eurozone. Bloomberg reports that
German Chancellor Angela Merkel said that she is willing to consider,
“…a…European redemption fund that would help governments scale back outstanding
debt to below 60 percent of economic output in return for constitutional
commitments on economic reform.” The difference between government debt
outstanding and that 60% would become the common liability of all Eurozone
members. This idea will more easily preserve the banking system and retain
country responsibilities. Note how this proposal handles two logical
incompatibilities, country autonomy and European solidarity, at two different
levels with reciprocal obligations. Greek elections are on June
17th.
2)
Iran - As in the Israeli-Palestinian negotiations, the principals are now
talking about trust-building measures. There is apparently a lack of trust
between both sides. According to the NYT, “Both sides are expecting the other to
take the first significant steps, without wanting to compromise on critical
issues…” Negotiations will convene again in Moscow on June 18th.
3)
U.S. - Reuters reports that the Simpson-Bowles proposals are now back on the
table. Messrs. Simpson and Bowles are working with a bipartisan group of “…47
Senators and as many House members to frame compromise on $7 trillion in looming
financial decisions.” Efforts to forge this compromise will occur after the
elections on November 6th.
The
discussion above illustrates that logical solutions to these problems exist, but
these solutions have to be negotiated. There have been greater difficulties. In
the 1950s, thermonuclear war threatened. If war had struck, the present value of
all investments would have been negative. However, in that decade, the total return of U.S. large cap stocks was +19.4% per year.
Since the U.S. was then the only major industrial economy in the world, we do
not think that the market will provide these sorts of returns going forward.
Nonetheless, this does illustrate that markets and investors can get used to
considerable long-term political risk provided the heavens do not collapse,
which they usually don’t.
__
Polling
in Greece, Germany, France, Italy and Spain indicates that 62% of all
respondents want to keep the Euro their currency. Ireland is the only Eurozone
country that votes directly to ratify a new European fiscal treaty; on 5/31/12
the voters approved its new budget control measures. The next day, the S&P
500 dropped 2.5% to 1278, slightly positive for the year. There are many
cross-currents in the world’s very complex economic
system.
We
assume that our readers have already adjusted their portfolios to suit their
circumstances and risk tolerances. The Eurozone can remedy its financial
problems by placing some form of guarantee upon its sovereign and banking debts.
If (or when) this occurs, the markets will rally. add: The Eurozone currently discusses a
central authority to manage its finances, new powers for the governing European
Commission, Parliament, and Courts, labor reform and so on. Too much, too soon. Much simpler to accept
the existing nation-state structure with a common redemption fund for all
Eurozone public debts in excess of 60%. (Germany’s Public Debt/GDP ratio
is currently 82%.)
__
Keynes
was not only a famous economist, but also an accomplished investor. At the
beginning of 1931, in a letter to the Board of the National Mutual, he
succinctly described the state of the markets and his thoughts on their
investment portfolio:
(1)
There
is a great deal of fear psychology about just now. Prices bear very little
relationship to ultimate values or even to reasonable forecasts of
ultimate values. They are determined by indefinite anxieties, chance
market conditions, and whether some urgent selling comes on a market bare
of buyers. Just as many people were quite willing in the boom, not only to
value shares on the basis of a single year’s earnings, but to assume that
increases in earnings would continue geometrically, so now they are ready
to estimate capital values on today’s earnings and to assume that
decreases will continue geometrically. (2)
In
the midst of one of the greatest slumps in history, it would be absurd to
say that fears and anxieties are baseless. As I have constantly said, I
consider the prospects of 1931 to be extremely bad. It is indeed only too
easy to feel frightened, and to find plausible reasons for one’s fears.
(3)
But
I do not draw from this conclusion that a responsible investing body
should every week cast panic glances over its list of securities to find
one more victim to fling to the bears…. (4)
Moreover,
the situation is quite capable of turning round at any time with extreme
suddenness. (Our note: This
is a major event reason why we aren’t selling.)…The introduction of a
tariff, a change of Government, and all sorts of things quite
unpredictable in advance will suddenly cause people to turn right around,
to appreciate how very cheap almost everything is, and to discover that
the market is completely sold out. (5)
I
believe, therefore, we should do well to make no more sales of securities
except for very special reasons. I feel this with much more confidence
because we have so thoroughly overhauled our list of late. Subsequent
falls in price are an increased reason for not selling, and not the opposite.
(Our note: This is the value investor philosophy.)
|
__
6/4/12 - German Chancellor Angela Merkel
suggests placing the Eurozone’s twenty-seven largest
banks under a single regulator. This will place “systematically important
institutions” under uniform regulation that will, as in the U.S., likely preempt
local regulation. The banks can also be more easily recapitalized. More
important, this takes cognizance of the fact that the large European banks are
multi-national, at the same time leaving room for local differences. (We’re only
discussing Europe. Charles de Gaulle said, “How do you govern a country where
there are 246 varieties of cheese?”)
__
Mr.
Fuerst (economics, Oxford) said he was skeptical
that Europeans would ever agree to delegate over their national budgets to
a European authority as part of a fiscal union. European leaders would be
better off concentrating on measures that are more realistic, he said,
like a common system for overseeing banks, guaranteeing deposits and
dealing with sick financial institutions. That
could help avoid situations like those in Ireland, Cyprus or now Spain,
where the cost of bank rescues raises doubts above the solvency of the
national government.
NYT,
6/11/12 |
After
the fall of the Berlin Wall in 1989, the socialist economies of the Soviet Bloc
restructured. In Russia, the “Big Bang” method of sudden and wholesale market
deregulation led not to a thriving market economy, but to wholesale corruption
and economic deterioration as the Oligarchs grabbed the assets of former
state-owned companies. The resulting economic chaos led the way, not to
democracy, but to the autocracy of the present Russian government under Vladmir Putin.
As
tempting as it may be to try to entirely overhaul a malfunctioning economy, this
is always not the best idea because, depending upon the
political culture, the social costs of doing so can be very high. Both “formal
rules” and “habits of thought,” work together to form institutions that guide
human interaction. The two should be as complementary as possible to. This
paper (Lenger, 2008) supports our contention that
culture determines the nature of the political and economic reforms possible.*
It would be much simpler and effective for Germany to focus more upon reforming
the Eurozone’s problematic financial
system.
* We recoded (to use a fancy word) the
author’s economic data on Table 3. This recoding found that all the countries of
the former Soviet Union adopted, or eventually adopted, gradual or no economic
reform. It also illustrates that with the exception of Slovenia, Hungary, and
Croatia (3) a majority of the more westernized Central European and Baltic
countries (6) adopted the Big Bang route to total economic modernization. The
point we wish to make is that societies, often after considerable turmoil,
develop the social structures most fitting to their own situations. This is not
to say that social structure cannot evolve, but reforms that are contrary to a
people’s historical experience won’t be successful. Transformational politics
must search for reform where previous history is familiar and positive.
__
The
recent Greek elections have given the pro-bailout New Democracy and PASOK
parties a majority in the legislature. Greece will likely stay in the Eurozone
and be able to renegotiate its austerity program. However, the Eurozone suffers
from a condition that has become acute.
The
Eurozone was founded in 1992 as a currency union, with the hope that it would
eventually evolve into a political union. But as Acemoglu and Robinson (2012) have written, the reverse is
actually true. Politics precedes economics. The Eurozone is likely too national and complex to become a new polity in the
foreseeable future.
Key
manifestations of the above are the problems of a single monetary policy and
fiscal control. Monetary policy can usually (but not always) accelerate or
retard economic activity to achieve a dynamic economic balance. Furthermore in
the United States fiscal spending is audited by the Office of Management and
Budget. The Eurozone, on the other hand, subjects its constituent countries to a
single European Central Bank interest rate regardless of national economic
conditions and does not audit its own spending. Monetary and fiscal controls are
not effective at the Eurozone level, thus there is now an acute financial crisis
in a number of countries that need to become more competitive.
A
minimum condition for financial stability is that the banking system be sound.
There is therefore good reason for the major European banks to be subject to
uniform ECB regulations, to cease bailing out their respective governments, and
for those governments to offload their excess debts to a common pool. But
granted stability, a problematic single monetary policy has to be somehow
remedied. The issue of fiscal control depends upon the Eurozone’s political structure and the nature of its
subsidies.
We
favor a low-risk portfolio income strategy because the macro situation in
Europe, although improved, still has to be resolved. Our own opinion is that the
Eurozone should try and centralize its banking system and otherwise decentralize
as much as possible.
7/1/12
-
The world has suddenly been afflicted
with an outbreak of rationality, exemplifying Keynes’ fourth reason for usually
staying invested (referenced above):
·
The
Eurozone leaders, at the 19th summit since the beginning of crisis,
approved the direct recapitalization of their banks. This agreement breaks the
link between banks and their sovereigns, in both their finances and eventual
regulation. Both Spain and Italy went into the conference saying they would
block all other agreements, including a $152 billion growth pact, until Germany
did something to remedy their short-term market plight. The meeting began on
Thursday. After an all-night session, Germany finally agreed to allow the
Eurozone Bailout funds to directly recapitalize the Spanish banks,
provided the European Central Bank set up a banking supervisory
body.
This
banking agreement finally establishes a required lender of last resort (Kindleberger, 2000 ed.). This BBC
article summarizes
the significant deal that has been reached.
·
The
U.S. Supreme Court voted 5 to 4 to uphold the constitutionality of the
administration’s signature Affordable Healthcare Act. By calling the healthcare
mandate a tax, rather than a regulation under the Commerce Clause of the
Constitution, the normally conservative chief justice, John Roberts, voted with
the liberal minority to avoid rejecting an act of Congress. This important
ruling reestablished the court’s non-partisanship in an election year.
The
U.S. government was the first in the world designed according to rational
principles. But one essential feature seemed to be lacking. How, from the clash
of partisan interests, is rationality for the system supposed to emerge? The
founders of the Republic sought, above all, to avoid the concentration of power
that could lead to tyranny. They therefore, using pluralist American society as
a model, divided it up. In Federalist #51, Madison famously wrote, “Ambition
must be made to counteract ambition….If men were angels, no government would be
necessary. If angels were to govern men, neither external nor internal controls
on government would be necessary.…This policy of supplying by opposite and rival
interests, the defect of better motives, might be traced through the whole
system of human affairs, private as well as public.”
But,
with private faction restrained by the balance of powers, how does the public
good happen? Madison identified the first cause, “…the great variety of
interests, parties and sects which it embraces, a coalition of a majority of the
whole society could seldom take place on any other principles than those of
justice and the general good…” * But, we think there is a second cause due to
the division of the United States government into the judicial, legislative, and
executive branches. That cause is time. Important decisions require the eventual
concurrence of all three branches of government; that tend in their respective
concerns towards the past, present, and future. Particularly at the level of
society, a good decision and a convincing narrative involve all three
perspectives.
*
By bargaining, unless obstructed.
__
So
what’s likely to happen in Europe? A recent newspaper article suggests the
possibility of disaster: 1) The German policy of austerity is likely to produce
a depression as everyone cuts back and 2) “…pride and prejudice make leaders
unwilling to see what should be obvious…. Europe’s leaders are, by and large,
neither evil nor stupid. But the same could be said…about Europe’s leaders in
1914. We can only hope this time is different.” Actually Germany’s Kaiser was
stupid and, furthermore, Europe’s geopolitical situation nearly one hundred
years ago was exactly the opposite of what it is now. It could be possible to
get a general sense of what might happen from the study of
history.
The
distance between London and Istanbul is around 1500 miles, roughly the distance
between New York City and Denver. In 1914, that distance spanned two democracies
(England and France), one dissatisfied monarchy with a
booming economy (Germany), and three empires that were not coping well with
modernization (Austria-Hungary, Russia, and the Ottomans). Life in that system
was complicated and insecure. After the Franco-Prussian War of 1871, Germany’s
chancellor Otto von Bismarck, structured an international system of changing
alliances that sought to avert a French alliance with Russia, with a vulnerable
Germany caught in the middle. This system kept the peace until it was
destabilized by the accession to power of Kaiser Wilhelm in 1888 whose blunders
realized Germany’s worst fears. The historian, Donald Kagan (1995), quotes a biographer:
The
last Kaiser’s most pronounced-and most fatal-characteristic was his
habitual inclination to act almost entirely on the basis of his personal
feelings. The most momentous decisions…his embracing the life and ethos of
a Prussian lieutenant, his implementation in the mid-1890s of a
reactionary domestic regime, and the campaign a few years later to
construct a gigantic navy-can be traced to vanity or to pique This
ineffable tendency to personalize everything stands revealed in the
Kaiser’s correspondence…on countless documents, which display passion but
rarely judgment. |
The
Kaiser then committed Germany to colonial policies and a naval race with Great
Britain that turned Europe into a tinderbox. The war then began with the
assassination of Austrian Archduke Franz Ferdinand in
Sarajevo.
Compare
the Europe of 1914 with the Eurozone now. Country boundaries have been settled,
a nucleus of inter-state cooperation exists, and the Brussels Summit has
resulted in a clear, but still general, commitment for bank recapitalization and
regulation. Crucial to the evolution of the Eurozone will be the quality of its
leadership. Germany is again front and center, but this
time as the Eurozone’s lender of last resort. The
current chancellor is the deliberate Angela Merkel, a PhD in physical chemistry
from the former East Germany. The following BBC article describes the challenges
she faces:
Chancellor
Angela Merkel appears to be holding all the cards – she presides over
Europe’s strongest economy and strongest government
finances. Any
rescue of the Eurozone therefore ultimately relies on German money. If
Chancellor Merkel provides the money too readily, she fears weaker
countries will keep coming back for more, while her own voters may lose
patience. But
if she does not provide the money, she risks letting the euro fall apart,
in which case Germany will face a catastrophe - massive losses on loans already
provided by the country’s banks, government and central bank to Southern
Europe, a collapse in demand from Germany’s biggest export markets, and an
angry political backlash from the country’s closest
allies. She
is trying to use her power, and the reliance on her country’s money, to
force through greater integration of the Eurozone, reasoning that this is
the only way to keep the euro together in the long-term.
|
Ms.
Merkel must undertake the difficult task of threading the needle between these
two essential extremes. Likely the worst that can happen is that the Eurozone
will muddle through for years, with its banking system stabilized. The best that
can happen is that negotiation, adjusting interest to interest, enables the
Eurozone to solve pressing problems, maybe on a more national basis, and restore
growth. The dawn of reason may
herald the day.
__
This
site is about the necessity of institutions and about the controlled creative
destruction of markets.* Forget about rational expectations theory (early
Enlightenment hyper-reason), that markets can foresee systematically significant
events. Maybe this is true in simple, well-defined situations; but the real
world is never at a static equilibrium. Consider the Eurozone crisis. In
spite of its known flaws: no lender of last resort, no foreign exchange rate
adjustment and no political union therefore no joint liability; the market
considered the default risk of all Eurozone sovereign debt to be minimal in
2007, see this graph.
Eurozone bond “analysis” neglected to thoroughly analyze the credit of each
country. The Financial Crisis of 2008 resulted in the default of Ireland and the
ongoing threat of a default by Greece. The market became (to use a psychological
term) “primed” to consider the possibility of defaults in other Eurozone
countries. The same graph shows that the later result was contagion, a massive
increase in the default risk of distressed Eurozone countries. Here, market
perceptions can affect reality, Soros (2008).
In
a period of financial distress, investors require clear and significant actions
by the lender of last resort. But:
1)
On
June 28, the Eurozone countries finally agreed to the direct recapitalization of
their banks by the €500 billion Eurozone Stability Mechanism, with ECB oversight
to be soon established.
2)
On
July 6, Reuters quoted a senior Eurozone official who, “…said that any direct
aid would require the sovereign in question to give a ‘full
guarantee.’”
3)
On July 9, the NYT wrote, “Reports last
week that national governments would still have to assume ultimate liability for
banks that are directly rescued with Eurozone bailout funds had taken some of
the luster off the deal reached by European leaders at a summit meeting in late
June…The interest rate… on Spanish 10-year sovereign bonds spiked above 7
percent again….The renewed uncertainty prompted the European Commission on
Monday to ‘clarify’ that ‘there will be no need for a sovereign guarantee for
banks being directly recapitalized by the soon-to-be-established permanent
bailout fund, the European Stability Mechanism.”’
Had
the Eurozone adopted bank recapitalization two years ago, there would be no
widespread crisis today. To get ahead of the curve, the Eurozone also has to
move to some form of limited or general debt guarantee acceptable to investors
in their state of mind.
A
2010 IMF report was
titled, “Default in Today’s Advanced Economies; Unnecessary, Undesirable, and
Unlikely.” The conclusion of this report, that there is no borrower benefit from
a default, remains valid. But it is very important that the markets not be
allowed to force a default in a panic.
*
In a 7/10/12 NYT article,
Liu and Hanauer drew the appropriate analogy. The
economy is not a machine; it’s a garden.
What
we require now is a new framework for thinking and talking about the
economy, grounded in modern understandings of how things actually work.
Economies, as social scientists now understand, aren’t simple, linear and
predictable, but complex, nonlinear and ecosystemic. An economy isn’t a machine; it‘s a
garden. It can be fruitful if well tended, but will be overrun by noxious
weeds if not…. Is
it possible to garden clumsily and ineffectively? Of course. Wise
regulation, however, is how human societies turn a useless jungle into a
prosperous garden. This explains why wherever on earth one finds
successful private companies, one also finds a well-regulated economy, and
where regulation is absent we find widespread poverty.
|
There
is an additional advantage to this analogy. There are English gardens, baroque
French gardens and Asian gardens. Voltaire wrote, “It is necessary to cultivate
our garden.” According to one interpretation of that enigmatic phrase, he was
expressing, “…an optimistic faith in the man who is capable of improving his
condition.” The use of critical
intelligence to improve one’s condition was the central practical goal of the
Enlightenment.
__
This
article
from Pimco is one of the best we’ve recently seen on
investment policy. Neel Kashkari answers two main
questions:
·
Given
the volatility of the New Normal, why should I invest in equities at all? Why
shouldn’t I just sit in cash and wait it out?
Unfortunately
the final end-state for the global economy following this debt-induced crisis is
unclear. If the global economy faces deflation, sitting in cash or fixed income
instruments will probably be the best option. Purchasing power will increase as
prices fall. While a deflationary scenario is not impossible, it is the least
likely outcome given central banks’ actions to date. More likely is a moderate
inflation scenario. Sitting in cash in such a scenario will see purchasing power
degrade due to inflation. Equities should perform well in a moderate inflation
scenario. This is our highest likelihood outcome….
Because
of the uncertainty regarding the end-state of the global economy and the fact
that the only scenario in our view where cash performs well is the least likely,
deflationary scenario, sitting on the sidelines is unfortunately not a good
option for those who have future liabilities (our note: requirements) they need
to meet.
Given
our outlook that moderate inflation is the outcome with the highest long-term
probability, we believe equities should be a meaningful part of a diversified
investment portfolio. Equity should continue to focus on higher-quality
companies with strong balance sheets that are selling into higher-growth
markets, including those that pay healthy dividends. (our note: like the multinationals.)
·
My
clients just can’t take the equity market pullbacks. What should I do as a
financial advisor?
Many
clients are in this situation. From May 2002 to May 2007, during the old normal,
the S&P 500 experienced a 5% correction from a recent high five times…and a
10% correction four times. In the three New Normal years from May 2009 to May
2012, the S&P 500 experienced seven 5% corrections, more than twice as
often, and a 10% correction three times. This increased downside volatility not
only has direct financial implications for clients, but also has indirect
effects that are important too. The emotional swings are scaring clients into
sitting on the sidelines. As discussed above, this could prove very costly if
central banks are successful in engineering moderate inflation, let alone high
inflation.
We
believe clients and advisors should focus on strategies that can be used to
manage downside volatility. There are a number of ways to pursue this: 1) Buying
higher-quality companies and those with strong balance sheets, because they tend
to more resilient against shocks…2) Buying companies at deep discounts to their
intrinsic value. 3) Buying companies offering more immediate return on
investment through dividends. 4) Actively hedging the portfolio, with tail risk
hedging (which refers to taking a defensive position against extreme market
shocks), or other means. 5) Investing in multi-asset solutions that provide
diversification and include equities, fixed income securities, and commodities
in one vehicle. (our note: value investing accomplishes
the first three. Active portfolio hedging, buying options, is very expensive;
unless you also sell options, which is complicated and risky. Market volatility
is still less than it was in 2008, which may not be saying much.)
What’s
going to happen in Europe?
The
crisis in Europe will take years to resolve in part because policymakers
there are trying to simultaneously achieve multiple, often-divergent
objectives: 1) preserve basic Eurozone stability. 2) keep pressure on fiscal authorities to make hard
choices and 3) keep inflation in check. These multiple objectives prevent
them from taking final, decisive action to quell the crisis. Our base case
outlook is continued spurts of crisis and volatility coming out of Europe.
These policy and macro factors will likely continue to overwhelm
company-specific factors in the short term. (our
note: of course, not in the long
term.) |
8/1/12 –
Is
this the start of severe financial system problems? We consider current problems
in order of possible significance:
1)
Eurozone
– Greece’s economy has declined to the point where its foreign trade accounts
are in balance. Its large budget deficit is a problem, which includes interest
charges. The remaining debt is 132% of GDP, with 60% ideal. Greece’s private
creditors have taken large chargeoffs, but its
government creditors have not and are unwilling to substantially renegotiate. On
July 24, the Troika of the EC, ECB, and IMF will visit Greece to discuss whether
to distribute the next tranche of €8 billion, enabling Greece to meet its
expenses and debt service until December. This debt collection process has gone
too far; we’re not sure what it accomplishes because Greece’s public creditors
are essentially paying themselves.
The
Eurozone has made Spain responsible for the new debt of its banks, in advance of
setting up uniform bank regulation. Again, we’re not sure what placing bank debt
upon the sovereign accomplishes, beyond delaying the inevitable – partial or
total joint assumption of debts. The Eurozone problem is a long-term condition,
whose solution awaits the formation of a political consensus.
2)
Iran
– Negotiations over Iran’s nuclear program seem to be deadlocked over the
phasing of various “confidence building” measures. The press reports that the
U.S. learned that Iran did not intend to give up its ability to build nuclear
weapons with highly enriched uranium. Iran has now stated its intention to build
a nuclear submarine, which must be beyond its technical capabilities. The
Iranian problem will be resolved in the short-term.
3)
United
States – faces the Fiscal Cliff. But there are now discussions in Washington
about how to climb down. One suggestion is to let the Bush tax cuts expire in
January. Taxes will increase, and then the Republicans will vote on middle-class
tax reductions, not violating their “No New Taxes” pledge to Grover Norquist. The Fiscal Cliff problem is short-term, that will
likely be resolved.
Each
of these events, taken singly, will likely not cause severe problems for the
U.S. markets. What is likely to cause severe problems would be the combination
of (1) with any of the others. We have stated the risks the best we can. In any
case, we don’t think that a systems collapse is likely; which of course would be
our main concern. We are furthermore long-term value investors. The best we can
do is state the short-term investment risks, and let our readers make their own
decisions whether to bear them.
9/1/12
–
Issues
of personal trust aside, Mitt Romney’s selection of Paul Ryan as his running
mate ties him even closer to the Republican party’s
ideological base. This election therefore offers the American people a choice of
which political philosophy, leading to more or less government, will best solve
the nation’s stubborn economic problem of low growth. The key question is
whether or not government can improve the investment results of the U.S.
economy.
At
the root of America’s present economic problems is the lack of profitable past
investments to create present jobs. For example, under the previous
administration the U.S. incurred more than 4,400 military casualties and a
liability of more than $3
trillion dollars (20% of 2011 GDP) in a generally unsuccessful effort to
bring liberal democracy to sectarian and tribal Iraq. More directly, driven by
the forces of unmediated globalization, U.S.companies
located a large fraction of their industrial bases abroad, resulting in a
massive tradable goods deficit of $738 billion in 2011 (representing lost U.S.
jobs) and resulting in a large domestic misinvestment
of resources in ultimately unproductive real estate and exotic financial instruments
that concentrated rather than dispersed risk. The resulting mania, panic and
crash resulted in the writeoff of a large fraction of
the U.S. financial system’s net worth and nearly destroyed the world’s financial
system.
The
analogy we make with portfolio management is apt. Misinvestment will reduce the long-term return of your
portfolio, creating consequences for years afterwards. The United States and southern
Europe both misinvested. From 2007 to 2011, the
U.S. economy grew by only .52% per year in real terms, with 3%+ typical.
Will
more or less government improve the growth of the U.S. economy? In 1776, Adam Smith published the Wealth of Nations, arguing that the
unrestricted free market economy best increases the benefits to society. In
1783, the Whig* leader Charles Fox gave a business reaction to Smith, “In that
book it was stated that the only way to become rich was to manage matters so as
to make one’s income exceed one’s expenses. This maxim applied equally to an
individual and to a nation. The proper line of conduct therefore was by a
well-directed economy to retrench every current expense, and to make as large a
saving during the peace as possible.” Fox summarized the business common sense
of Smith’s book. This would probably be Mitt Romney’s reaction as well, after a
career in leveraged buyouts.
But,
of course, that is not all. Fox did not mention Sir Issac Newton (1642-1727) at Cambridge. The role of business
is to make things happen in the short-term, but societies also require
investments for the long-term. This is why education, government-sponsored
research and infrastructure matter very much. Education is the path to the
future, for it allows the next generation to think well and differently to adapt
the country to new circumstances. Government-sponsored research at the National Institutes of
Health and Darpa provide the fundamental scientific understandings
necessary for new products. (Bell Labs, formerly owned by
the communications monopoly AT&T, invented the transistor, the laser, made
major advances in communications theory under government contract, and developed
the widely used C computer language.
In 2006, Alcatel-Lucent acquired Bell Labs. In 2008, the scientific
journal Nature reported that only
four scientists remained in basic physics research.) Infrastructure is the
public road on which private benefits travel.
To
grow the United States economy, long-term investments are necessary. Short-term
markets and businesses competing in those markets simply do not provide them.
Markets and businesses worry about earnings next quarter. Keynes noted this fact
in 1933, and it is true today. The rest of the world is getting more capable;
the U.S. must up its game.
*
The Whigs were a 17th century English political party that
represented the growing commercial interests, in opposition to the Tories that
represented the landed interests. After the revolution, there was also a Whig
party in the United States.
__
Boiling
down the Republican convention to its few specifics, Mitt Romney’s convention
speech suggested he would do two things besides abolish present healthcare
reforms: “…reducing taxes on business (our note: also on all)…simplifying and
modernizing the regulations that hurt small businesses the most.” In essence, he
proposes reducing the size of government to Paul Ryan’s goal of 20% of GDP. At a
time of considerable resource underutilization, that will likely increase
unemployment and further retard economic growth.
Do
federal government expenditures as a percent of GDP determine the degree of
economic recovery and growth? We think not, at least not within a wide range.
The German government sent Ruprecht Polenz, chairman of the foreign policy committee of the
German parliament as a convention observer. Here are his observations:
Americans
have a fundamentally different view of social policies; also in their
relation to…what the state should do….And the Republicans emphasize this
very specifically. For us, it was always hard to fathom – and many may
have not even been aware of it – that before Obama’s healthcare reform, a
large number of Americans had no health insurance whatsoever. For Germany,
that is really incomprehensible. We simply have to chalk this up to an
essentially different mentality. But I also have to say that the U.S.
vice-president (our note: candidate) has announced as a goal a 20 percent
public expenditure quota [ratio of government consumption to GDP – the
ed.]. Ours, in Germany, is more than twice that. I think therein
lies the difference, in a nutshell, between our understandings of state
and private… |
Are
the Germans groaning under “big government?” Apparently
not. According to World Bank statistics, from 2007 to 2011, the German
economy grew at an annual real rate of 1.13% per year, as opposed to .53% per
year for the United States (The World Bank uses a slightly different base than
the U.S. to calculate real economic growth.) The structure of Germany’s export
economy differs from the United States’ consumption economy. During a time of
slow economic growth around the world, their growth rates are not high; but
still higher than ours. The Republican ideology of minimal government is
certainly no law for economic growth.
The
Wikipedia table, International Government Spending…, shows if you
consider all (federal, state, and local) government expenditures as a
percent of GDP, the U.S (38.9%) is in the middle range of all countries. Use the
table symbol ♦ to sort the data. The real
question is how well government funds are spent.
__
A
real plan should reasonably relate to real social conditions.
__
Why
did Siemens AG (Germany's General Electric) locate a new large turbine
manufacturing plant in North Carolina, generating 825 new
jobs?
A
9/4/12 Washington Post article
indicates that it was mainly due to public sector factors:
Ask
Siemens executives why they placed their bet on Charlotte and they talk
about public investments such as the state-funded rail spur that runs
through their facility (our note: to transport the large turbines) and the
city’s international airport (our note: to transport management from
Charlotte to Munich), which recently added a fourth runway using $132
million in federal funds. They
talk about the Export-Import Bank, an independent federal agency that in
January approved a $638 million loan to finance the sale of turbines to
Saudi Arabia, helping Siemens beat bids from companies in Germany, South
Korea and Japan. And
they talk about the quality of the workforce in Charlotte, where local
leaders are retooling the public education system to churn out the
engineers and skilled technicians needed to operate one of the most
efficient gas-turbine plants in the world. “A
lot of things that were offshored in the past
were offshored because of lower-cost labor, but
that’s no longer the most important factor,” said Eric Spiegel, president
and chief executive of Siemens’s U.S. subsidiary.” The reasons you bring a
plant like this to the United States are higher-skilled labor, access to
the world’s best research and development, and good, sound infrastructure.
All those things together make the U.S. a good place to
invest.”… “What
we’re seeing globally is we have a real opportunity to bring a wide range
of jobs back to this country-including manufacturing jobs-because you see
an acceleration in labor costs in other markets,” said Dean Garfield,
president and chief executive of the Information Technology Industry
Council, which represents 50 of the worlds
largest tech firms. “To the extent we get the right policy mix, we can do
a lot to encourage locating as many jobs as possible here in the United
States.” (and)…”You
don’t hire people just because there’s a tax credit here…You hire people
if there is demand…to produce
more.” |
From
this article, we can see that a number of factors result in wealth-generating
regional industrial growth. Tax policy is barely mentioned. Market forces and
government investments in education, research and development and infrastructure
are gradually restoring lost manufacturing jobs to the United States. These are
highly skilled and well-paid jobs, likely available mainly to those who have
just graduated. The U.S. has exported its mass production abroad, and it will
not return. What about those who are presently unemployed? A combination of
relevant retraining in different fields and individual incentives will likely be
the most effective. A set of pragmatic, unimpeded, policies should make possible
general economic growth.
Concentrating on the essential: this election is choice between growing the economy from the middle out, where everyone gains; or from the top-down, where only a few will.
__
We
trimmed back slightly on stocks sold a stock on 9/18/12 for valuation
reasons. We shall comment on add: broad investment issues next month.
10/1/12 –
As
a value investor, our major concern is whether the intersection of untoward
events in the Eurozone, the Mideast, and Washington could lead to a 2008 systems
breakdown. We think that is unlikely.
Eurozone
On
9/15/12 FT reported:
Global
stock markets were buoyed yesterday as confidence grew that central banks
had acted decisively to buttress the European and US economies, while
averting a possible euro-zone break-up. European
shares hit highs not seen for more than a year. On Wall Street, the
S&P 500 extended an advance that has pushed the index to its highest
level since late 2007.
|
Recent
developments * have largely taken the major market risk of an Eurozone systems breakdown off the table. This is a major
effect.
Iran
Nuclear
talks with Iran have apparently stalemated, with the U.S. drawing a line at the
act (rather than their capability) of building a nuclear bomb, that may be
manifest a year or more hence. The Iranian leadership, as has been reported, is
rational. The Iranians should therefore be incented to seriously negotiate if
the pain of widespread international sanctions and the likelihood of further
action exceeds the possible gain in national power and
security from having a nuclear bomb.
Iran
has devoted extensive national resources to their program; they are unlikely to
give it up. But they could agree to limit it, and then abide by the agreement.
**
Washington
Will
Washington compromise on the budget after the elections, thus avoiding the
“fiscal cliff”? According to present discussions,
perhaps. ***
More
generally, in almost any society and most of the time, decisionmakers are expected to keep the system running and
make life better. Disruptive innovation is good in business, but it is not good
in politics because it carries very high costs. In market societies, it is the
role of the political system to facilitate, regulate and ameliorate the creative
destruction of the economic system.
Some Facts We Note:
* The Eurozone crisis
illustrates that additional research can dispel some uncertainty. The Eurozone’s most recent “moment of truth” came on 9/12/12
when the German Constitutional Court approved Germany’s €190 billion
contribution to the European Stability Mechanism, dismissing a blocking motion
brought by 37,000 plaintiffs. This decision also made further contributions
subject to parliamentary review, freeing Chancellor Angela Merkel to use German
funds to support reforms in the rest of the Eurozone.
Before
the fact, how would the German
Constitutional Court have likely decided? A review of membership indicated
that it is comprised of twelve judges (eight were involved in this ruling), many
from the German academic community with two of the judges educated at the law
schools of Harvard and Michigan. We had a sense that the court might rule in
favor of the Eurozone.
**
Iranian society is much more divided
than is North Korea. The negotiating strategy likely takes this into account.
***
The elections on November 6th will give the winner a mandate to deal
with the deficit. This 9/20/11 Washington
Post article
suggests a compromise will be in the offing, with the ideologues in the House a
problem.
__
A
9/30/12 NYT article by Thomas Friedman sums up the situation
well:
Add
it all up and it’s a world in which America will have greater
responsibility (because our European and Japanese allies are now
economically enfeebled) and fewer resources (because we have to cut the
defense budget) to manage a more complex set of
actors… This
complexity doesn’t argue for isolationism. It argues for using our powers
judiciously and in a nuanced fashion.
|
11/1/12 –
We
recently attended a Stanford Business School reunion. We noted the teaching of
Silicon Valley’s ‘disruptive innovation”, or Schumpeter’s “creative
destruction”, and discussions about the Eurozone.
Innovation
How
would you design a new product for farmers in the developing world? They are
discerning customers who, by definition, have low incomes. You would go through
the following analysis to produce a profitable product:
1)
Understand
the problem by talking to people.
2)
Observe
the problem’s context. (The analysis here will take into account a number of
factors.)
3)
Most
important, establish a point of view.
4)
Develop
a prototype.
5)
Test
it. (Iterate the design.)
Education
is the economy’s path to the future. In a 10/16/12 NYT article, Thomas Friedman
notes, “…we needed to move to some form of universal postsecondary education to
keep pace with globalization and I.T., we didn’t. Instead…‘our high school
graduation rates stopped improving and our growth in college graduates slowed
substantially – far below what we needed for rapid growth and shared
prosperity.’” Mohammed El-Erian writes that school
curricula need to be, “…more global, interactive and
engaging...”
Eurozone
The
economic problem du jour is Europe.
Central bank intervention has taken the risk of wholesale default off the table,
but the Eurozone has fundamental organizational issues. If liberalism is a
reasoned form of government, and the Europeans live in liberal democracies, then
they should be willing to reason themselves to effective political and financial
compromises. Some very knowledgeable professors and European alumni suggested,
not. An attendee noted that the United States is more than 200 years old (and
its history has not been without problems). In contrast, the Eurozone is only
twenty years old; and its member states are loath to compromise because their
publics do not have a political allegiance to it and therefore do not perceive a
shared future. This unfortunate situation suggests the following train of
events.
Since
The Eurozone countries are unwilling to compromise and write off each others’
debts (our modest suggestion), the most likely set of events will be a grinding
process somewhat akin to a loan workout, where the financial system slowly earns
its way out of debt, aided by the financial repression of 0% interest rates. But
since Germany will demand economic reforms akin to those that it has implemented
domestically, the Eurozone will lurch in a series of crises to force compromise
among different cultures. The mistake the founders of the Eurozone made was to
place economics before politics, to think that economic integration would result
in political integration. Our article, “Economic Theory and Social Reality,”
describes exactly the opposite process. The Eurozone’s
14.2% share of the world’s 2011 GDP is the second largest in the world. Europe
is a continuing concern, but should not bring down the world’s economic
system.
Markets
and Politics
At
present, the bond markets do not accurately reflect the fundamentals in the
world’s economy, due to expansive central bank monetary policies that buy
time.
Bond prices are too high. The U.S. stock market more accurately reflects the
prospective long-term level of economic growth. We shall discuss the investment
implications of this and the consequential outcome of the November
7th elections. Politics is not the same as economics. There is a need
for a gradual political treatment to restore economic confidence and to
allow the patient’s recovery to continue, not an ultimately “severe”
conservative ideological agenda.
__
Since
the Crisis of 2008, we have been investigating in detail the interaction between
politics and economics. This concern can be summarized by an equation of change
and growth:
Disruptive Economic
Innovation + Political Innovation = k, a constant
In
this formula, the more of one, the less of the other.
It says that businesses will invest in the future and grow if they can be
assured a stable political environment. If the political environment is very
innovative, that is the description of revolution. How do revolutionary
conditions affect economic growth? The answer is, not well.
Describing
French economic conditions after the Revolution, historian Simon Schama (1989) wrote, “In 1795, the total value of France’s
trade was less than half what it had been in 1789; by 1815 it was still at about
60%. The momentum of economic and social change in France only picked up as the
Revolution and the military state it created in its wake disappeared.” (This is
the description of the equation above.) After the Russian revolution of 1993,
that country’s GDP then dropped by 20% between 1992 to the trough in 1996. Now,
consider the economic effects of the “Arab Spring”. According to the European
Union *, the real GDP of Egypt decreased from 5.1% in 2010 to .6% in 2011; the
real GDP of Tunisia (where it all began) decreased from 3.7% in 2010 to -.7% in
2011.This is simply to say that revolutions, regardless of their reasons, have
high economic costs, and should not be undertaken lightly.
The
best solution for societies, if possible, is the slow evolutionary political
change advocated by Edmund Burke. That requires the interests of all be
respected. This is why Americans have traditionally seen themselves as
shareholders in their society.
*
Article in the 10/9/11 FT.
__
On
November 6, President Obama won both the electoral and popular votes, thus
obtaining from the American people the approval to continue economic reform.
This election averted the libertarian ideology of minimal government. The
practical American electorate realized the Republicans had no effective steering
link between their minimalist values and the track of a real policy appropriate
for the interrelated 21st century.
The
goal of monetary policy throughout the world is to buy time, and its success
will depend on how that time is used. Since the country has once again
reiterated that it is practical, will the Republicans abandon their “no new
taxes pledge” to Grover Norquist, thus lending their
useful perspectives to policy that the government always needs to be more
efficient and that direct hiring occurs at the local level? Or will they
continue to obstruct necessary long-term government investment? There seem to be
few new investment opportunities in the U.S. because we have not made the
necessary long-term commitments to education * and research. Here, the social
issues of inequality and immigration become relevant. The U.S. should reach out,
both developing and importing more talent to grow its economy. It can’t do this
while preserving existing economic interest behind the fortress of political
oligarchy, all in the name of freedom.
The
political history of single-minded ideologues, whether in Washington or
elsewhere in the world, is not encouraging. When faced with defeat, they simply
try harder. We truly hope that the loyal opposition will start trying to solve
problems in the real world, a task for which they were also elected.
*
This is not an abstract issue. Quoting the 10/24/12 Business Week:
A
Council on Foreign Relations Independent Task Force report…concluded that
American Schools “are not equipping the majority of students to
effectively participate in an increasingly fast-paced and interdependent
global society.” The
report found that only 4.5 percent of U.S. college students graduate with
engineering degrees; in China, 33 percent do.* Beyond hurting American
economic competitiveness, the knowledge gap is affecting the ability of
the U.S. to defend itself. Among eligible high school students, 30 percent
score too low on the Armed Services Vocational Aptitude Battery to qualify
for military service. *
We had to verify this astounding comparison. We traced the data
to a National Science Foundation report. The gist, if not the percentages,
is correct. In 2008, the U.S. granted 69,908 bachelor’s degrees in
engineering out of 1,580,413 undergraduate degrees (4.4%). China granted
704,604 degrees in engineering out of 2,256,783 degrees (31.2%). Look also
who is staffing the STEM (science, technology, engineering, and math)
graduate departments in the United States.
|
In
the 19th century, the United States built its economy on 1) the
opening of new markets and natural resources as the nation expanded westward 2)
waves of immigrants (to operate a very disciplined
mass-production industrial system) and 3) technological change. Now, in the
21st century, it must rely mainly upon technological change
add: and a technologically adept work force for growth in an increasingly
developed world.
Manufacturing
requires a high degree of appropriate social organization. An 11/23/12 NYT
article discusses BMW:
In
1987, a recent engineering graduate named Norbert Reithofer (currently the CEO) wrote a treatise that in
retrospect reads like a manifesto for the German economy. The only way
manufacturers in a high-cost country with few natural resources could
survive, he argued, was by becoming the most flexible and efficient in the
world….Next year, BMW plans to introduce a battery-powered car with a body
made primarily of carbon fiber and aluminum. These materials are lighter
than steel but much more costly to deploy in a mass-produced car.
The
effort…is especially risky given that sales of electric cars like the
Nissan Leaf have been disappointing so far. But Mr. Reithofer said he saw …(the) car that will be built in
Leipzig, Germany, as a way of preparing the company for long-term changes
in the industry….”If you can’t build in a place, then you can’t innovate
there either…” |
BMW
could invest in the future because it is profitable in the present. The electric
car might be presently more appropriate in Europe, where gas costs the
equivalent of $8 per gallon. By analogy, according to data in a MIT article,
recent oil shale discoveries in the United States could substantially reduce oil
imports by 4.2 million barrels per day by 2020. This would reduce the trade
deficit by $130 billion/year out of a total of $560 billion in 2011. But the experience of the United States with the Dust Bowl of the 1930s shows
that it is not wise to fool with Mother Nature. The federal government
had to literally rebuild the prairie states after agricultural excesses. As
Hurricane Sandy illustrates, the long-term consequences of global warming are
becoming manifest. Growth and sustainability, economic social and ecological,
could be balanced policy goals.
From
a balanced position, the U.S. will better have the ability to shape change and
thus its future.
__
(We deleted a
11/7/12 excerpt on current tax policy for the above discussion.)
12/1/12
–
Rules
of thumb are practical. Yet they involve implicit assumptions. Take, for
example, the asset allocation rule that the percentage of bonds in your
portfolio should equal your age. This rule is simple, and meets the common sense
test that the amount of risk you take should decrease with your age.
The
Gordon Model analyzes the long-term components of stock market returns. It is
derived from the rigorous present value model for valuing financial assets. The
simple Gordon model is best used when evaluating high-dividend paying companies,
with stable growth rates and leverages, over a very long time period. The
model states that:
A
Stock’s Investment Return =
Present Dividend/Price + The Nominal Growth in Dividends
(Earnings) after Inflation
|
This
model enables us to separate the components of the S&P 500’s past investment
returns, and thus to arrive at an estimate of its future returns. To assess the
accuracy of this model in the real world, we utilize stock market data for the
55 years between 1947 and 2002, when returns were distorted neither by major war
nor financial crisis.
Real GDP Growth
($1.8 trillion in 1947, $11.6 trillion in 2002, BEA
statistics)
Annual Inflation
(1947-2002, Ibbotson)
S&P 500
Dividend (1947, quarter 1, S&P Statistical Service 1992)
Calculated
Annual Return of the S&P 500 during Period
|
3.4% 3.9%* 4.7% 12.0% 12.9% |
A
90 basis point understatement of return in any particular year may seem
insignificant. Yet over a 55 year period, that slight return differential will
compound to a 1.55X understatement of future stock value ($1.00 will compound
790.98 times vs. 509.32 times). We are going to use the Gordon model because the
following comparison is striking:
Projecting
forward into the future:
Real GDP Annual
Growth (avg CBO estimates) Annual
Inflation (Cleveland Fed estimate)
S&P 500
Dividend (current)
Estimated Annual
Long-Term Return of the S&P 500
|
2.3%** 1.5%
2.1% 5.9%
|
Due
to lower economic growth, inflation and higher stock prices the estimated
long-term return of the S&P 500 is around one-half the return in the past.
This
is also true of the bond market. Between 1947-2000 the
return of long-term corporate bonds was 6.1%. The current yield of best-grade
corporate bonds is 3.6%.
So
what does this do to the asset allocation rule? These statistics seem to suggest
that investors should dump all low-returning and likely more risky bonds in
favor of stocks, as low as their likely returns will be. We think this is not a
good idea. It violates the first rule of prudent financial management, that
investors should keep their assets somewhat diversified (What if the whole world
tips into recession again?). The second reason for maintaining the general asset
allocation rule is that it can be tweaked, to somewhat ameliorate the low
long-term returns of stocks and bonds. Here is what we are
doing:
1) Stocks – Value companies have sustainable competitive advantages, moats around their markets, and sell at bargain prices. The philosophy of value investing uses more reliable near-term balance sheet and historical cash flow information to determine value, rather than optimistic projections. For large cap stocks, we use a discount from calculated value of 33%. ***
2)
Bonds
- The Fed’s interest rate repression has reduced short-term returns to 0% and
long-term returns to a very low level. (If you have a laddered portfolio of
medium-short-term bonds, the problem will cure itself
over time as you replace maturing short-term bonds with longer term ones.) This
had led to an increased investor interest in “alternative assets”, that is
assets that they don’t generally understand. We suggest another alternative for
current yield.
Publically
traded master
limited partnerships generally engage in activities involving natural
resources, such as pipelines. Pipeline MLPs provide high 6-9% distribution
yields and are described on pages 613-624 of the current Value Line®.
We would invest in these equity partnerships (here considered debt) only in
conjunction with a bond portfolio, because excessive industry concentration is
not a good idea in an income portfolio. These investments should not be held in
IRAs or 401(k)s and should be bought for keeps. A large
proportion of the ancillary tax benefits available under current law will be
recaptured by the IRS as ordinary income if these investments are sold. They
should always be bought on their fundamentals. Make sure that the leverage is
not excessive and that management makes related acquisitions for sound
operational reasons. add: By investing in
pipeline MLPs, we’re also moving along the risk curve. If the market drops, so
will the MLPs (but likely somewhat less). Their distribution yields are very
high. We realistically assume that the U.S. economy won’t entirely fall apart.
We
have suggested that the asset allocation rule should be modified by taking on
(some) increased risk, as is the Fed’s intention. add: It is simplest to consider this minor
modification to the asset allocation rule an exception, for exceptional
circumstances. Also, know what you are invested in. Our next posting in January
will discuss the future of the U.S. economy.
To
note again the purpose of this website.
The purpose of this website is to publish research about the markets and the
interaction of such with the political order. To comply with the Uniform
Securities Act and state regulations, we have to write for general purposes
only. For advice that is related to your specific situation, we encourage you to
speak with a qualified investment advisor. After reading these articles and
postings, you will be an informed and challenging client; but do be aware of all
sorts of costs as well. Generally, the simpler the
better. We recently attended a national brokerage firm’s presentation
of complicated structured financial products that bundle life insurance, “Run,
don’t walk…”
*
If you use annual data between 1968 and 1999 to analyze the willingness of
people to invest in stocks, the
inflation coefficient is negative. That is, an increase in inflation is even
worse for stocks over the short-term, when the bond markets are crashing. If you
analyze the returns of the stock market, over decades, then stocks are a hedge
against inflation. There is a difference between short-term and long-term
analysis.
**
The Bureau of Economic Analysis estimates that real economic growth in the U.S.
will be below historic levels. The major issues are entitlements, high debt
levels and the need for structural economic change to emphasize growth rather
than consumption.
***
In Value Investing (2001) page
144, Bruce Greenwald presents a modified present value model that
determines a company’s value from its operations (return on capital), required
return (cost of capital), and conservatively estimated growth. The result will
be the company’s intrinsic value, the value of a franchise that management is
tasked to maintain and grow.
__
Growth
is a function of labor, capital and how these inputs are used to produce GDP.
According to a 12/5/12 NYT article,
insufficient demand chips away at labor, capital and productivity thus reducing
investment and therefore future growth.
Keynesian
economics is mainly demand-side management. We think there is a further
structural supply-side problem; current demand also leaks abroad, resulting in
increased imports (GDP = …+Exports-Imports). The problem facing the U.S. here is
the same as that facing many other countries. The U.S. has to increase public
and private investments and the inventiveness * of its industrial
economy.
*
Why are people inventive? In the November, 2012 Foreign Affairs Magazine, Neil Gershenfeld writes about the Digital Fabrication Revolution,
“To be able to invent, people need to question assumptions.” That sentence is
the (unfortunately then unstated) reason why we had to take Freshman English and
Western Civ as core requirements many years ago. The
purpose of those courses was Socratic, but it wasn’t just to examine life. It
was to establish a habit of questioning that is the cornerstone of innovation.
Mass
production is now in Asia. U.S. innovation is likely to be in the highly capital
intensive process industries such as energy and biotech and in decentralized
manufacturing that is flexible, innovative and of course networked.
__
The
U.S. system of shared political power is supposed to produce real policy
appropriate for the times, not ideology. It solves engineering problems in the
real world *, not physics problems in theory. The role of the state
is to enable a diverse people to live together, not to pursue – as in
traditional non-democratic societies – “virtue,” that is of course my values. In
The Sense of Reality (1997), Isaiah
Berlin humorously wrote:
To
be rational in any sphere, to display good judgement in it, is to apply those methods which have
turned out to work best in it. What is rational in a scientist is
therefore often Utopian in a historian or a politician…Botany helps
gardeners, laws of dietetics may help cooks, but excessive reliance on
these sciences will lead them – and their clients – to their doom (Berlin
essentially argues against an impersonal logic or technique applied to
human affairs). |
Markets
(whether political, economic or financial) require a balanced diversity of
participants who will freely do business with each other according to common
rules or procedures. If all the world were either value
or momentum investors, the markets would not error-correct and thus
self-destruct. The present fundamentals of the U.S. economy are improving. As
long-term investors, we are not overly concerned with short-term issues; but
Washington does have hurdles to clear to achieve a consensus on the budget and
thus a way forward.
*
What makes an engineering design work in the real world
is the appropriate laws invoked.